Betweenness and the Rise of Moscow


These are notes on "The Medieval River Trade Network of Russia Revisited"  by  Forrest Pitts. Published in Social Networks (1978/79) 1:285-292

Here is a map of Russia in the 12th and 13th centuries:

Figure 1. Russian trade routes in the 12th-13th centuries.

 

Figure 2. Graph of Russian trade routes in the 12th-13th centuries. Moscow is #35

Many historians have written about Moscow's gradual rise to a position of dominance over other towns. Most claim that the growth was a response to favorable geographical conditions. The Russian historian Kluchevsky (1911) comments:

"The political fortunes of Moscow were closely connected with its geographical position." (p.273)

"Thus Moscow arose at the point of intersection of three great land roads - a geographical position which conferred important economic advantages upon the city and its neighborhood. ...Boyars always followed the currents of popular migration, so that their genealogical records are evidence that at that period [time of Daniel, youngest son of Alexander Nevsky, circa 1270 AD.] the general trend was toward Moscow. This steady influx into the city, as into a central reservoir, of all the Russian popular forces threatened by external foes was primarily due to the geographical position of Moscow." (p.276)

"Immunity from attack, so rare in those days [circa 1240 - I 360], caused the eastward movement of Russian colonization to become reversed. That is to say, settlers began to flow back from the old-established colonies of Rostov to the unoccupied lands of the Principality of Moscow. This constituted the first condition which, arising out of the geographical position of Moscow, contributed to the successful settlement of the Moscovite region Another condition which... contributed to the growth of the Principality was the fact that Moscow stood upon a river which had always - even from the most ancient times - been possessed of great commercial. importance ... a waterway connecting the system of the Middle Oka with the system of the Upper Volga. ...By thus making Moscow the point where two great popular movements intersected one another - namely, a movement of colonization northeastwards and a movement of commerce southwestwards, the city's geographical position conferred great economic advantages upon the Moscovite Prince. A large population attracted to his appanage meant a large number of direct taxpayers, while the movement of a large volume of commercial traffic on the Moskva meant a stimulation of popular industry in his dominions and a large flow of transit-dues into his treasury." (p. 278)

The American historian Blum (1961) added:

"The success of the Muscovite house seems best to be explained by a combination of the favorable geographical location of Moscow and lots of good luck. Their capital lay at the intersection of important overland routes, while the Moscow River, on whose banks the city rose, connected the two chief river systems of European Russia." (p.67) "Merchants came there from all parts of Russia and from abroad to buy and sell, and foreign visitors from the latter fifteenth century on were impressed by the amount of business activity they observed. From Moscow merchandise was shipped in every direction, sometimes traveling hundreds of miles before reaching its destination." (p:125)

In this paper the physical network of rivers is first of all a transportation network. The medieval Russians traveled the rivers by boats in summer and with sleds over the river ice in winter. But the river network supported social interaction. Trading of slaves, amber, honey and furs produced economic networks. Marriage alliances and religious exchanges both produced and strengthened social networks. And the frequent interaction permitted the Russian language to spread and become dominant over a wide area.

By way of reprise, the results reported by Pitts (1965) are summarized in Table 1. The connection array results arose from the powering of an adjacency matrix (in which entries are 1 if two places are adjacent on the river net, 0 otherwise). In this view Moscow ranks fifth among the 39 places. The short-path array was calculated by determining the minimum number of intermediate links between each pair of places. Its results show Kolomna as the best connected place, with Moscow ranking second.

Table 1

Connection Array   Short-Path
Actual Percentage Place Actual Rank
2652 0.51 Novgorod 176 35
3574 0.68 Vitebsk 172 32
9521 1.82 Smolensk 148 17.50
5303 1.01 Kiev 173 33
8691 1.66 Chernikov 181 36
10181 1.95 Novgorod Severskiy 162 28
14703 2.81 Kursk 160 26
26898 5.15 Bryansk 130 9
18662 3.57 Karachev 157 22.50
41022 7.85 Kozclsk 116 4
24001 4.59 Dorogobusch 121 7
36292 6.94 Vyarma 113 3
11282 2.16 "A" 132 11
14843 2.84 Tver 128 8
5184 0.99 Vishniy Totochck 158 24
19451 3.72 Ksyatyn 118 5.50
6883 1.32 Uglich 152 20
3114 0.60 Yaroslavi' 184 38
3415 0.65 Rostov 182 37
8150 1.56 "B" 148 17.50
3711 0.71 "C" 174 34
4249 0.81 Suzdal 163 29
10344 1.98 Vladimir 133 12
4518 0.86 Nizhniy Novgorod 161 27
1394 0.27 Bolgar (Kazan) 198 39
7101 1.36 Isad'-Ryazan 156 21
8135 1.56 Pronsk 159 25
8671 1.66 Dubok 157 22.50
9248 1.77 Elets 170 30
23936 4.58 M tsensk 141 15
17717 3.39 Tula 145 16
21015 4.02 Dedoslavi' 131 10
13414 2.57 Pereslavi' 134 13
39478 7.55 Kolomna 104 1
26663 5.10 Moscow 107 2
22016 4.21 Mozhaysk 118 5.50
9954 1.90 Dmitrov 151 19
13681 2.62 Volok Lamskiy 138 14
3515 0.67 Murom 171 31

Rather, I prefer to regard the sum of all short-path Euclidean distances for a place (node) as a measure of accessibility, in the sense that it represents the effort to go between that node and all other nodes via the shortest paths. When divided by the sum of all short paths in the system, it becomes a percentage of effort within the system of places.

When one counts the number of times a short path between two places passes through an intermediate node, one obtains what Shimbel (1953:507) calls stress. At the conclusion to his paper, Shimbel wrote:

"If we count all of the minimum paths which pass through site k, then we have a measure of the "stress" which site k must undergo during the activity of the network. A vector giving this number for each number [i.e., site] of the network would give us a good idea of stress conditions throughout the system."

Shimbel concluded his 1953 article by saying: "This 'stress' vector can derived directly from the structure matrix but unfortunately the process is not simple" (p.507). The algorithm for the derivation of the short-path node listing was later described by Dantzig (1960), and programmed by Scott (1967) in the middle 1960s.

Shimbel's stress idea was generalized by Freeman (1977) as a betweenness index. If a node falls on the only minimum path or on all the minimum paths linking a pair of other nodes it is tabulated twice in Shimbel's index and once in Freeman's. On the other hand, a point that falls on one of several shortest paths linking a particular pair of others is not tabulated in the stress index but is weighted in proportion to its occurrence in the betweenness index. Of course if there is only one minimum path connecting each pair of points the stress measure is exactly twice the betweenness measure. Under this condition Scott's (1967) Minpath program calculates both stress and betweenness times two.

However, when there are several minimum paths connecting any pair of nodes, Scott's program does not calculate stress. If there are no more than two minimum paths connecting any pair of points, Scott's index is still equal to the betweenness index times two. But if more than two minimum paths exist anywhere in the network, the Scott algorithm does not calculate either stress or betweenness it does not even generate a unique solution.

In the present application there were never more than two minimum paths linking any pair of nodes, so Scott's intermediate node occurrence rate was used along with his aggregate distance of each short path. These two sets of results are presented in Table 2.

Although stress or betweenness measures one aspect of a network of communication, the system effort required in moving from one place to all other places by the shortest paths between them is in a sense a reciprocal measure. System effort, however, is not determined by betweenness in theory. The relation between these measures for the Russian river network is shown in Figure 3. There it is obvious that the intermediate node occurrence rate has a greater variance, and is a more discriminating measure of node centrality. The percentage of system effort is, on the other hand, a good measure of node accessibility

Table 2. Intermediate node occurrence rates and
short-path distances for the Russian rivernet

  Place INOR Aggregate
short-path
distances
Percent
INOR
Percentage of
agg. short-path
distances
1 Novgorod 0 7179 0.00 4.11
2 Vitebsk 11 5647 0.22 3.23
3 Smolensk 119 4247 2.39 2.43
4 Kiev 0 7704 0.00 4.41
5 Chernikov 30 6244 0.60 3.57
6 Novgorod Severskiy 96 5052 1.93 2.89
7 Kursk 0 5768 0.00 3.30
8 Bryansk 288 4062 5.80 2.32
9 Karachev 86 4240 1.73 2.42
10 Kozclsk 163 3753 3.28 2.15
11 Dorogobusch 377 3596 759 2.06
12 Vyarma 268 3411 5.39 1.95
13 "A" 101 4077 2.03 2.33
14 Tver 228 3745 4.59 2.14
15 Vishniy Totochck 61 4795 1.23 2.74
16 Ksyatyn 410 3788 8.25 2.17
17 Uglich 0 4395 0.00 2.51
18 Yaroslavi' 2 5047 0.04 2.89
19 Rostov 72 4697 1.45 2.69
20 "B" 231 4208 4.65 2.41
21 "C" 74 4242 1.49 2.43
22 Suzdal 73 4056 1.47 2.32
23 Vladimir 186 3939 3.74 2.25
24 Nizhniy Novgorod 93 5216 1.87 2.98
25 Bolgar (Kazan) 0 8640 0.00 4.93
26 Isad'-Ryazan 119 3742 2.39 2.14
27 Pronsk 64 3846 1.29 2.20
28 Dubok 48 4091 0.97 2.34
29 Elets 6 4500 0.12 2.57
30 Mtsensk 44 4520 0.89 2.59
31 Tula 90 3517 1.81 2.01
32 Dedoslavi 205 3468 4.13 1.98
33 Pereslavi 107 3498 2.15 2.00
34 Kolomna 339 3009 6.82 1.72
35 Moscow 531 2876 10.69 1.64
36 Mozhaysk 321 3108 6.46 1.78
37 Dmitrov 24 4071 0.48 2.33
38 Volok Lamskiy 74 3683 1.49 2.11
39 Murom 28 5194 0.56 2.97
  TOTAL: 4969 174851

With regard to the growth of Moscow, we may say that it has a structural or topological advantage in having the highest betweenness index in the system as well as the lowest proportion of system effort devoted to river travel. I would assume that a structural advantage of this sort would become a social and economic advantage. Whether this actually occurred is for historians to debate, but their considerations must now take into account the results reported here.

Figure 3.